Fair Markets for Rural America

The role of anti-monopoly policy in mending the urban-rural divide

Photo and illustration elements: Ljupco, oticki, seamartini (iStock)

Every election season, red and blue maps reinforce the myth of “two Americas,” the wealthy, liberal cities and the declining, conservative countryside. Pundits paint rural communities as economically stagnant, predominantly white, deeply bigoted places that vote against their own interests and deserve either pity or scorn. This narrative erases the diversity of rural America as well as the commonalities between urban and rural Americans struggling with historic economic inequality and unchecked corporate power. 

While the urban-rural divide may seem insurmountable, it is much newer than pundits would lead you to believe. Stark rural polarization only began in the mid-1990s, spurred at first by economic stagnation brought on by globalization and neoliberal policies, and then deepened with the rise of partisan media and what scholars have identified as a growing rural resentment.

But as with urban inequality, rural stagnation is not inevitable; it is a policy choice. One neoliberal policy mistake that hit rural and urban economies hard was the death of anti-monopoly enforcement. Since the 1980s, both parties have allowed corporations to buy up rivals and use illegal exclusionary business practices. Decades of unchecked monopolization hurt small businesses and innovation and have given corporations more power to raise or fix prices.

A post-neoliberal economic platform demands new labor, trade, and tax policies; but in this essay, I will focus on examples of state-level anti-monopoly policy. Rural voters across the political spectrum disdain monopolies and corporate greed, particularly in agriculture, and support government action to promote fair competition. From cracking down on repair monopolies to leveling the playing field for independent grocers, state lawmakers have many options to combat corporate consolidation and exploitation in rural America.

 

Let people fix their things 

Farmers’ incomes can depend on harrowingly narrow windows of opportunity: They have a couple of days of ideal conditions to plant their crops, apply fertilizer, or harvest before an unexpected freeze or rain ruins everything. The last thing they want during these make-or-break sprints is for their tractor to give out.

Take the case of Jared Wilson, a farmer in Missouri who needed to apply fertilizer quickly after extreme rain set back his usual routine by two months. Wilson’s John Deere fertilizer spreader should have been able to do the job, but he discovered an issue with the hydraulics during a system check. Wilson needed to run more diagnostics to identify the source of the problem, but he could not access John Deere’s proprietary diagnostic software himself, so he had to bring his machine, full of fertilizer, to the dealership. When those repairs took longer than expected, Wilson couldn’t afford to ship his equipment to the next closest dealership, roughly 80 miles away. In the end, Wilson’s spreader stayed in the shop for 32 days, which prevented him from applying much fertilizer that season and cost him two to three days of planting. Wilson thinks the whole ordeal and lost time cost his operation $30,000 to $60,000. Deere identified that his problem was a mechanical valve, which Wilson believes he could have fixed himself, had he had the schematics and diagnostic tools.

Much like today’s automobiles, modern farm equipment is full of computerized parts and software. Digital barriers prevent farmers from diagnosing issues or completing repairs themselves. Some error codes completely shut down tractors until an authorized technician comes to plug in their computer, figure out what’s wrong, make the fix, and unlock a digital key to complete it.

Corporations like John Deere have, in effect, monopolized the repair of their equipment, which is highly profitable for them (with profit margins as much as five times those of equipment sales) but devastating for farmers who cannot afford to wait hours, days, or even weeks for a fix. Farm equipment manufacturers often do not have enough authorized technicians to cover peak demand periods like planting and harvest, exacerbating delays right when farmers need repairs most. One report estimated that tractor downtime and higher repair costs cost U.S. farmers over $4 billion a year. Farmers increasingly seek out tractors from the 1970s and 1980s that they can fix themselves without a computer. In 2020, 45-year-old tractors with low mileage sold for more than $40,000, and even $60,000.  

John Deere isn’t the only corporation that figured out it pays to control repair. Life-saving medical devices, home appliances, and electronics all increasingly include software locks or proprietary parts that only the original manufacturer or authorized techs can get around. These restrictions shut out local independent repair shops that could provide more timely or affordable service. Centralized repair particularly hurts people in rural areas who must travel farther or wait longer to get things fixed. The idea that you or your neighbor can’t tinker with your property offends a rural value of self-reliance. 

Photo and illustration elements: JackF, Ljupco, seamartini, sergeyryzhov, sirapob (iStock)

Letting people fix their things has widespread and bipartisan appeal. All 50 states have introduced bills over the last eight years to ensure that consumers and independent shops can access the manuals, diagnostic software, parts, and tools necessary to repair things, but only six have passed them. Of these six, no bill is universal: Massachusetts’s law covers cars; California and New York’s laws cover electronics; Colorado’s bill targets agriculture equipment and consumer electronics; while Minnesota and Oregon’s bills cover most consumer goods except farm equipment. Of the 29 states that introduced right-to-repair bills this legislative session, 21 would protect farm equipment.

Farm equipment carve outs, and failed bills, demonstrate the lobbying might of manufacturers like Deere to fight right-to-repair. During the 2023 legislative session, the president of the Nebraska Farmers Union joked that “there was hardly enough room in the rotunda” for all of the farm equipment manufacturers’ lobbyists. These bills also draw opposition from Big Tech lobbyists and other corporate interests that can easily overwhelm state legislatures. However, it is important for state legislators to keep pushing for right-to-repair laws that cover all critical equipment, especially the farm machinery that puts food on the table. 

 

Ending big-box favoritism in the grocery business  

Walmart and dollar stores like Dollar General are having significant impacts on local businesses, particularly in rural communities. Studies find that Walmart and dollar-store openings correlate with nearby small-business closures and long-term community income and employment decline that, on net, cost households more than they save on cheap goods. 

Walmart particularly dominates rural grocery markets. The chain sells 25% of all groceries nationally and in 2019 it sold 50% of groceries in one in three so-called micropolitan areas—population centers outside big cities. As Walmart and other large chains came to dominate food retail, rural food access has gotten worse. Before the 1980s, for example, nearly every small town in North Dakota had a grocery store or two. Today, half of rural North Dakotans live more than 10 miles from the nearest grocery store. More communities lack access to full-service grocery stores now than in 2010. Policymakers have created many incentives to bring grocers to underserved rural communities, with lackluster results. 

Walmart and other consolidated national grocery chains have some scale economies that help lower prices. But they also get better sales terms from wholesalers because they have the market power to demand them. Independent grocers can offer fresh produce for the same price or less than big-box retailers, but they generally can’t compete on shelf-stable products, because even the largest consumer packaged goods companies lack the bargaining power of Walmart. During the pandemic, Walmart demonstrated how this works, threatening suppliers with a penalty for late or incomplete deliveries, which in turn diverted more scarce goods to Walmart while shorting other retailers. Albertsons recently told its suppliers that it will not accept cost increases due to tariffs without prior authorization, which could force suppliers to make up their losses by charging more to less powerful buyers. 

A federal law, the Robinson-Patman Act, bans special pricing concessions based on brute bargaining power. It says that any discounts or promotions need to be based on demonstrable cost savings, such as bulk discounts for larger orders that lower per-unit shipping costs. Independent grocers often form buying clubs to buy in larger, more efficient volumes, yet even then they pay more for wholesale than some chains sell at retail. Federal antitrust enforcers only recently started cracking down on Robinson-Patman violations after generations of non-enforcement.

States can step in if federal enforcers sit back. For one, state attorneys general can use existing federal law to bring Robinson-Patman charges. But they only have the authority to make businesses stop their price discrimination; state enforcers cannot levy other penalties like fines (except in very specific circumstances). 

States can thus introduce local prohibitions on price discrimination that go beyond federal law. Minnesota recently introduced a bill, with bipartisan co-sponsors, that would create an expanded state-level version of the Robinson-Patman Act, specifically for the grocery sector. The law would ensure that all grocers can acquire goods for similar prices, on equal terms, if they meet efficient order minimums and use lower-cost purchasing methods. This would reduce prices at independent grocers, which are more likely to serve rural communities left behind by large chains. The law gives the state attorney general and private grocery suppliers or retailers authority to seek injunctions and civil penalties for violations. 

 

Strengthening healthcare merger review 

Decades of unchecked mergers and acquisitions have allowed a few corporations to corner the market for essential goods and services, driving up prices and stifling competitive innovation. While the federal government is generally responsible for blocking mergers, state attorneys general have underutilized authority to intervene in deals that would harm their residents, either by joining federal suits or bringing their own. Colorado and Washington recently made headlines for challenging the proposed grocer mega-merger between Kroger and Albertsons, citing concerns that the deal would lead to higher prices and store closures across their states. Washington won its suit, as did the federal government, successfully blocking the deal.

States have proposed legislation to give attorneys general more authority and resources to conduct costly merger reviews. New York, California, Minnesota, and Pennsylvania have all introduced legislation to make it easier for states to challenge mergers and go after other unfair corporate conduct. One market that could particularly benefit from more state-level merger enforcement is healthcare. 

Nearly every part of the healthcare system, from hospitals and insurance to medicines
and pharmacies, has consolidated since the 1990s. Healthcare consolidation harms rural communities by driving service cuts and hospital and pharmacy closures. The federal government considers 80% of rural America “medically underserved.” Rural patients must travel farther and farther to seek healthcare, and increased travel times are associated with worse patient outcomes and higher mortality rates
in emergencies. 

Rural healthcare providers, especially hospitals, struggle to remain profitable serving fewer and fewer people who tend to be older with higher levels of chronic illness. Rural hospitals feel pressure to merge to survive. Between 2005 and 2016 alone, there were 380 rural hospital mergers implicating 12% of all rural hospitals. Nearly 30% of rural communities report experiencing a large hospital chain coming in and buying up a local provider. 

Sometimes a merger is the only option to keep a rural hospital afloat, but in other cases, mergers drive rural hospital closures and service cuts. One study found that struggling rural hospitals were more likely to stay open if they affiliated with a larger healthcare system, while financially stable rural hospitals faced a higher risk of closure if they affiliated rather than remaining independent. For instance, the Pennsylvania Health Access Network found that one in three hospital mergers and acquisitions in the state since 2004 eventually led to a full or partial hospital closure. Merged hospitals and rural hospitals acquired by larger healthcare systems are more likely to eliminate maternal care, surgery departments, on-site diagnostic imaging, primary-care services, and outpatient non-emergency visits compared to independents. 

Studies also find that hospital consolidation increases costs as hospitals face less local competition. Larger hospitals also use their market power to lower workers’ wages, which particularly hurts rural economies where local healthcare systems can be major employers. 

Healthcare is a good example of an industry in which local mergers can seriously decrease competition and raise prices for lifesaving services, but regional deals may not meet the federal threshold for antitrust review. As such, most states require that healthcare companies give advance notice of a merger, but only 16 states have passed laws to give their attorney general (or another agency) special authority to review and approve healthcare mergers. This gives states more power to block deals they believe could raise prices, decrease care, hurt local jobs, or otherwise harm constituents.

About The Author

Claire Kelloway is the food program manager at the Open Markets Institute and primary reporter for the Food & Power newsletter. Her writing has appeared in Vox, Time, Mother Jones, the Intercept, and ProPublica. She lives in Minneapolis.

Subscribe below for updates from The States Forum

Other Articles

Policy in Motion

Message from the Founders: First Principles in the 11th Hour

Power-Sharing Liberalism

The Stranglehold of Interest-Group Taboos

Subscribe below for updates from The States Forum